Do I Really Deserve Even More Of Your Money?

The Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) have once again expanded the services provided under Medicare. New coverage of ultrasound monitoring of cardiac output today, new treatments for congestive heart failure yesterday, and, undoubtedly, some new cancer treatment tomorrow.

As a baby boomer nearing Medicare eligibility, I’m hoping to benefit from some of these many new treatments promising a longer life and a healthier old age. New technology might even help reduce Medicare costs, though past history argues against that rosy result for most improvements. Getting more usually means paying more.

Who will pay for my additional benefits? Current law suggests you—at least, if you are in your prime working years. I’ll pay a premium in retirement that covers perhaps one-eighth of the insurance value of my Medicare and potential Medicaid long-term care benefits. Benefits now are so extensive, especially relative to past Medicare taxes, that most of us baby boomers are already scheduled to reap huge transfers from you who are younger. A typical couple retiring in 2020, for instance, will have paid about $100,000 in lifetime Medicare taxes (much less if we don’t credit them with interest on their past contributions). For that price, this couple is scheduled to receive about $500,000 in lifetime Medicare benefits over and above the premiums it additionally pays in retirement.

Is there a better business plan? You bet. A basic principle of governing is that we should pay for what we get, unless a case can be made for government to interfere and require others to pay. But by what rationale should you be paying ever more for me? If it’s some notion of transferring from the haves to the have-nots, including the poor or those who can’t work, you should know that, like most of my generation, I’m not poor and am quite capable of work. True, many capable and relatively young retirees look poorer because they stop working—as you would if you stopped working—but, even then, the poverty rate of retirees today is well below that of children.

The lure of new benefits as an incentive to stop working aside, the case for you providing my generation increasingly more benefits over time certainly isn’t progressive government—that is, unless “progressive” just means bigger. Indeed, promising to pay me so many additional benefits every year now pushes government to scrimp on education, after-school activities, and a whole host of other needs for groups of people, including children who truly are needy.

The driving force here is not some rational democratic budget procedure for determining which of society’s needs are most pressing and whether government remedies are appropriate. Instead, medical benefits now compound automatically and so quickly that they force other programs to compete for leftovers that shrink as those benefits grow.

It’s not that government-run health insurance should avoid financing health care improvements. But why should you keep footing the bill by default when I’m the one who’s enjoying the longer and better life? And why should my needs for an ever larger share of your money trump society’s many other needs?

I can help pay for what I reap by giving up some early retirement and health benefits to pay for added benefits later, perhaps by working longer and, thereby, paying more taxes. Look at the private model. If I want my 401(k) account to pay out an annual benefit that grows by 6 percent a year until I die, as opposed to a level benefit, my mutual fund or bank or insurance company simply reduces my up-front benefits to pay for that annual boost.

Medicare is more complicated, but the analogy is still apt. If I have to pay for some of the built-in growth but think that the cost is too high, I’ll have more reason to demand that government better control costs. But as long as I can simply shove the costs to you, the incentive is to take all I can get—that is, if I don’t care how little government provides for the needs of my children, my grandchildren, and their world.


Pension Plan Discrimination Against the Short-Lived

Many pension plans pay out benefits over a worker’s remaining life. Perhaps inadvertently, they then discriminate against groups with shorter life expectancies. Losers include those with poorer health, less education, and more physically demanding jobs. Racial groups with higher mortality rates, like blacks, also lose. This discrimination, however, can largely be overcome with compensating mechanisms.

Retirement plans are of two types. One type revolves around deposits to such accounts as 401(k) plans and individual retirement accounts (IRAs). Typically, when employers pay compensation to this type of retirement plan, the benefits are proportional to cash wages and of equal benefit to all workers at the same wage level. The more classic pension plan, on the other hand, has a formula for “replacing” wages over a worker’s remaining life. For instance, a firm might pay workers with 30 years of service an annual benefit equal to 20 percent of pay earned during their highest earning years.

At first the classic pension plan might appear to treat equally those workers with the same jobs, wages, and time with the firm. But it does not. Why the discrimination? Converting benefits to annuities gives those with shorter lives fewer benefits than those with longer lives.

Generally speaking, we want to encourage annuities. They do a lot of good things. As death is a random event, most pensioners are happy to get the extra protection in case they live long lives. Annuities help prevent our living standards from falling as we age. Social Security, for these reasons, pays out benefits as an annuity to meet its social policy objective of “insuring” for those with long lives.

Still, consider the extreme case of George, who is in poor health throughout his life, works for a firm for 30 years, gets no survivor benefits, and dies at eligibility age. The firm would pay George zero pension benefits. Meanwhile, Paul, who is in very good health and can expect to live a long life, receives substantial pension benefits. The discrimination isn’t just among individuals, like George and Paul, but also among groups. Blue-collar workers might do worse than white-collar workers and blacks worse than whites.

Social Security shows us that it is possible to deal with this type of discrimination through offsetting mechanisms. For instance, Social Security has a progressive benefit formula that provides higher benefits relative to past lifetime earnings (higher “replacement wages”) to those with lower-than-average lifetime earnings. Because lower earnings are correlated with lower life expectancy, people from educational, racial, and other groups with lower life expectancy are more likely to get equal returns on their Social Security contributions or taxes

Unlike Social Security, classic pension plans don’t have access to lifetime earnings records, so they can’t use the same offsetting formula. To provide equal pension pay for equal work, other offsetting mechanisms must be tapped. A simple example is life insurance, which tends to favor those with lower life expectancies. An adequate amount of life insurance provided in addition to the classic pension plan could compensate some of those who lose out because of the annuity feature of the plan. However, such life insurance would need to carry forward beyond employment years since people with shorter life expectancies often do make it to retirement age.

Another simple compensating device would be to require that annuities contain a certain minimum number of years of payments to heirs if the worker dies. Such “life certain” policies can insure, for instance, that even if a worker dies at retirement age, at least 15 years of payments would be made. These rules could also be used to insure more equal treatment of those with lower-than-average life expectancies who convert their 401(k) and similar balances into annuities. Firms sometimes increase the probability that benefits will be paid for at least some years by providing survivor benefits, but those benefits often don’t help single workers.

While classic pension plans have been on the wane in the private sector, millions of government workers participate in such plans. Federal, state, and local governments could examine and amend these pension plans to reduce discrimination among their own workers. Similarly, protections should be put in place for those purchasing annuities with their 401(k) and similar accounts. Future retirement and pension plan reform must start to address this discrimination. Short lived shouldn’t mean short changed.